Monthly Archives: March 2013

BLS: Unemployment Rate declined in 22 States in February

 

From the BLS: Jobless rates down in 22 states, up in 12 in Feb.; payroll jobs up in 42 states, down in 8

Regional and state unemployment rates were little changed in February. Twenty-two states had unemployment rate decreases, 12 states had increases, and 16 states and the District of Columbia had no change, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reported today.

California, Mississippi, and Nevada had the highest unemployment rates among the states in February, 9.6 percent each. North Dakota again had the lowest jobless rate, 3.3 percent.

State Unemployment Click on graph for larger image in graph gallery.
This graph shows the current unemployment rate for each state (red), and the max during the recession (blue). All states are below the maximum unemployment rate for the recession.
The size of the blue bar indicates the amount of improvement – Michigan and Nevada have seen the largest declines – New Jersey is the laggard.
The states are ranked by the highest current unemployment rate. No state has double digit unemployment and the unemployment rate is above 9% in only seven states: Mississippi, California, Nevada, Illinois, North Carolina, Rhode Island and New Jersey. In early 2010, almost half the states had an unemployment rate above 9%.
The unemployment rate is falling quickly in some states like Nevada and California. As an example, the unemployment rate in Nevada has fallen from 12.1% in August 2012 to 9.6% in February 2013.

BLS: Unemployment Rate declined in 22 States in February
Bill McBride
Fri, 29 Mar 2013 15:19:00 GMT

Advertisement

Iceland in the Year 2050

That’s there’s climate changes seems clear, but its implications are less so.

The NY Times reports a type of James Bond story as a mysterious Chinese zillionaire seeks to purchase a large amount of rural Iceland to erect a snowy golf course.   Do you smell Dr. No?  I don’t.  I see a climate change adaptation bet.   Arbitrage is to buy low and sell high.  Perhaps because he read Climatopolis, Huang Nubo is making an investment that could earn a high return if Iceland’s quality of life improves relative to the rest of the world as climate change plays out.    New challenges create new opportunities.  While the NY Times views this story as just “weird”, I think it is a nice example of how those who form expectations of the future act upon those expectations.  Mr. Nubo could lose on this investment but he is experimenting and there are plausible scenarios under which he will become even richer. 
It is certainly possible that his “golf course” is an attempt by China to claim property rights to minerals that might be under the ground but any land owner always has this option.  I ask my students to solve for a price of gasoline such that Beverly Hills home owners would knock down their homes and drill for gas underneath the surface.  

Iceland in the Year 2050
Matthew Kahn
Sat, 23 Mar 2013 16:20:00 GMT

Two foreign policy initiatives contrasted

 

Michael Giberson

Two foreign policy initiatives, both began in mid-March, one a year old and the other started ten years ago, have had dramatically different effects on the world. Eric Shierman celebrates the wiser of the two efforts:

I have considered writing about the Iraq War on the tenth anniversary of our collective, bi-partisan decision to make one of the greatest strategic mistakes in American military history, but it’s just too depressing to put words into sentences describing the cost in lives and treasure we paid….

Thus the most encouraging anniversary to reflect on is not our invasion of Iraq ten years ago this week, but the wise implementation of our free trade agreement with South Korea one year ago. … From that body of peer reviewed literature [on foreign relations] there has emerged little empirical evidence of a correlation between peace and the pursuit of ever greater military strength among states, but there is overwhelming evidence that the single most powerful pacific force in foreign policy is trade….

The empirical evidence is just overwhelming, … the more exposed people are to complex trading economies with a higher degree of specialization and division of labor, the more empathy they employ in their decision making and the more rational they are in seeking their own selfish ends through the voluntary cooperation of others. It’s not enough to know what you want; successful exchange requires a focus on what others’ want as well. This paradigm spills over into other aspects of our lives even when we are not aware of it.

Of course this is not the primary goal of free trade agreements, economic growth is. The pacifying effects of trade are merely a positive externality….

Worth reading the full thing.

Two foreign policy initiatives contrasted
Michael Giberson
Fri, 22 Mar 2013 13:41:06 GMT

Time: The Relentless Pursuer that Kills us All (eventually)

 

Wait for it.

Time
Mon, 25 Mar 2013 00:00:00 GMT

John Taylor’s austerity model

One of the best writers on the web at boiling down macroeconomics for a general audience is Noah Smith who provide the post below.  Even so I’ll try to boil this down more.

He comments on John Taylor’s WSJ article arguing that fiscal austerity would aid the economy.  The assumptions that this relies on are:

1. taxes have big supply side effects.  Reductions in transfers and reduced taxes will increase the incentive produce and actual production.

2. The demand side impact will be offset by the expansionary policy by the Federal Reserve.

3. The Fed will be able to do step to because interest rates are not at some minimum bound.

Noah I think considers 3 to be problematic and that makes 2 problematic.  In the end it all relies on strong incentive effects of tax cuts, so in short the Taylor article is really a simulation with a close lineage to 80’s supply side economics.

John Taylor, possibly more than any other economist who writes in the press, likes to simplify things for public consumption. Personally I think this is kind of a shame, since A) any WSJ reader who understands economic models will not understand what Taylor is talking about until they actually go read his research, and B) any WSJ reader who doesn’t understand economic models probably already believes that “austerity = good”, and doesn’t really care if there’s a DSGE model backing up the assertion.

Fortunately, your friendly neighborhood Noah is here to read and explain where Taylor is getting his arguments.

In today’s column on austerity, Taylor writes:

This week the House of Representatives will vote on its Budget Committee plan, which would bring federal finances into balance by 2023. The plan would do so by gradually slowing the growth in federal spending without raising taxes.

Still, the plan has been denounced by naysayers who assert that it would harm the economic recovery and that, at the least, any spending reductions should be put off until later. This thinking is just as wrong now as it was in the 1970s…

According to our research, the spending restraint and balanced-budget parts of the House Budget Committee plan would boost the economy immediately. With the Budget Committee’s proposed tax reform included, the immediate impact would be even larger…

Our assessment is based on a modern macroeconomic model (developed with Volker Wieland of the University of Frankfurt and Maik Wolters of the University of Kiel)[.]

A modern macroeconomic model! Watch out, kid, you could put someone’s eye out with that!

(Random note before we get started: The “1970s” reference is pure conservative herp-derpery. People weren’t trying to fight stagflation with fiscal policy in the 70s; deficits were quite low. “The 70s” is just a word that conservative writers throw into their pieces so that conservative old men who read the article will nod their snowy heads in sage agreement and mumble “Yes, the 70s. Carter. Stagflation. Mmm-hmm!”)

OK, but I digress. Why does Taylor think austerity will produce growth? The article doesn’t tell us a lot about the aforementioned “modern macroeconomic model,” so let’s go to the source. Here it is

Taylor’s paper basically uses a Smets-Wouters type DSGE model, i.e. the most popular and successful DSGE model in existence at the moment. It’s a New Keynesian model, which means that demand shocks exist and have an effect, through sticky prices, and hence monetary policy matters. So it’s not a “freshwater” or RBC-type model (though Taylor et al. do also show that their results hold with an RBC model, somewhat unsurprisingly). 

In other words, Taylor’s model is not the type of model that many (including myself) have criticized for being too easily biased toward conservative policy conclusions. Instead, it is a very mainstream type of model, of the kind usually used to justify the Fed’s role in managing aggregate demand. Of course, Taylor uses it for something quite different.

So anyway, I’m not going to copy the equations from the paper, because that would just bore you, and you can just read it yourself. However, I’ll try to summarize. The upshot of the paper, as Taylor said in his WSJ piece, is that a certain kind of austerity plan would be good for the economy in both the long-run and the short-run.

Here are the basic things you should know about where Taylor gets his results:

1. This is NOT the “Treasury View.”

The “Treasury View” is the simplistic and wrong idea that any dollar spent on “stimulus” has to be one dollar not spent by the private sector, and hence government spending is incapable of raising output. Taylor is not espousing this view. In fact, as we’ll see, in Taylor’s model changes in government spending most definitely can affect output.

2. This is NOT the “Confidence Fairy.”

The “Confidence Fairy” is the idea that uncertainty over future government policy restrains investment, and usually involves the notion that austerity decreases policy uncertainty. However, Taylor’s model doesn’t have policy uncertainty in it.

3. The economic boost of austerity comes entirely from tax cuts.

Taylor’s model has distortionary taxation in it, and the distortions are large. Hence, spending cuts mean lower taxes and hence less distortion, both now and in the future. In other words, the GDP boost in Taylor’s model doesn’t come from reducing the deficit, it comes from cutting taxes. The government’s long-run budget constraint, along with forward-looking expectations (the same force that powers “Ricardian Equivalence” in other models), means that spending today –> taxes tomorrow –> distortions tomorrow –> distortions today because of forward-looking expectations.

4. The “Sumner Critique” is in this model.

Normally, New Keynesian models of this type focus on finding the optimal monetary policy. But since Taylor is looking at fiscal policy, he assumes that monetary policy is set according to an unchanging rule.  OK, I’ll put in ONE equation. Here’s the rule:

This is a backward-looking Taylor rule with interest rate smoothing. Unfortunately, in this working paper I can’t find what values Taylor uses for the coefficients on output and inflation. But he does put in some coefficients, that’s for sure.

Remember, this is a New Keynesian model with sticky prices, so aggregate demand does matter. But Taylor assumes that the Fed is already doing pretty much everything a New Keynesian would have the Fed do.  So in Taylor’s model, the Fed cancels out most aggregate demand shocks, including positive demand shocks from stimulus. So it’s hardly surprising that Taylor is not going to see government spending doing much good for the economy; he’s assumed that 1) the Fed is perfectly capable of managing aggregate demand, and 2) the Fed will tighten to partially counteract stimulus. This is just a softer version of the common “Sumner Critique” of fiscal policy, though of course Taylor probably didn’t get it from Sumner.

5. There is no Zero Lower Bound.

Note that in the monetary policy rule written above, there is nothing that says that interest rates can’t go negative. In other words, Taylor assumes what most New Keynesian models assume, which is that there is no Zero Lower Bound (or that we’re always far from it). Any of you who are familiar with the New Keynesian DSGE literature will recognize that Taylor’s result is a very common result in this literature: Away from the ZLB, fiscal policy is not very effective. The “New Old Keynesians” such as Paul Krugman and Gauti Eggertsson, who advocate fiscal stimulus, explicitly make reference to the ZLB as the reason stimulus works. Taylor just ignores that idea in this paper.

6. In Taylor’s model, if you cut government purchases, it throws the economy into a recession.

Taylor’s suggested austerity plan makes big spending cuts, but the cuts are almost entirely cuts in transfers (like entitlement payments or welfare) rather than in government purchases (like infrastructure spending). Here’s a picture of Taylor’s austerity plan:

Now as you should remember from Econ 102, government purchases make much more effective stimulus than transfers, because government doesn’t buy the same things that people would buy if you just mailed them checks (but people still receive the checks). So any Keynesian would expect cuts in transfers to be much more benign than cuts in government purchases. In fact, the difference between purchases and transfers is a consistent theme in Taylor’s work, which makes me think he’s more Keynesian than he makes himself out to be. But anyway, let’s take a look at what Taylor’s model says would happen if we implemented austerity through reductions in government purchases instead of cuts in transfers:

Wow! In Taylor’s model, implementing austerity by cutting government purchases would throw the economy into a deep recession. The reason he gets short-run benefits from spending cuts has everything to do with the fact that it’s almost all transfers being cut.

6. In sum, Taylor’s result is a standard New Keynesian result.

Upshot: If you have no Zero Lower Bound, and if the Fed partially counteracts the demand-side effects of fiscal policy, and if people have forward-looking expectations, and if you don’t cut government purchases much, and if taxes are very distortionary, then austerity works. This is not really a new result, but it rarely gets shown so explicitly, so it’s good that John Taylor and his co-authors went ahead and did it.

That said, the result basically ignores the real Keynesian critique that has emerged since 2008, which is that the Zero Lower Bound matters a lot. It also probably assumes that taxes are a bit more distortionary than they really are. And it also probably overestimates the Republicans’ real willingness to cut transfers (entitlements are the “third rail”, after all), and underestimates their willingness to cut government purchases. In real life, spending cuts usually fall on the things that are politically most easy to cut, but are economically most valuable in both the short and long runs – infrastructure and research. Finally, Taylor’s plan ignores distributional concerns, but that’s pretty much par for the course.

(Oh, also, neither Taylor’s model nor the RBC or Keynesian alternatives includes nonrival government capital (public goods). But that’s not the point I’m trying to make here. Oh, and also, modern macroeconomic models – and any other macroeconomic models currently in existence – don’t actually come close to describing reality. But that’s also not the point I’m trying to make here.)

So John Taylor is not committing some major fallacy. He’s just using a standard mainstream New Keynesian DSGE model to stump for the Republicans.
Update: Miles Kimball says that Taylor’s result is basically all about the monetary policy reaction function (i.e. the equation I posted above). Furthermore, Kimball notes that Taylor has supported a tighter monetary policy, in direct opposition to the kind of Fed reaction function he assumes in the paper. In other words, if Taylor got the monetary policy he wants, then his own DSGE model would go *poof* and suddenly austerity of the transfer-cutting type would become much more harmful.
Update 2: A commenter points out that in Taylor’s simulations, real interest rates never fall below zero. That means there’s something odd about the parametrization, since real short rates are negative right now. But I don’t know where the oddness comes from.

John Taylor’s austerity model
Noah Smith
Tue, 19 Mar 2013 08:25:00 GMT

Voyager 1

 

So far Voyager 1 has 'left the Solar System' by passing through the termination shock three times, the heliopause twice, and once each through the heliosheath, heliosphere, heliodrome, auroral discontinuity, Heaviside layer, trans-Neptunian panic zone, magnetogap, US Census Bureau Solar System statistical boundary, Kuiper gauntlet, Oort void, and crystal sphere holding the fixed stars.

Voyager 1
Fri, 22 Mar 2013 00:00:00 GMT

Image

A Great Dilbert

strip.print

Music Mondays: Guster–Amsterdam

Music Monday: U2–Pride/City of Blinding Light

Heritage on Seasonal Adjustment

 

Is February employment growth overstated due to statistical problems?

From “February Employment Report: Has the Economy Seen Its Shadow?,” by James Sherk and Salim Furth, a discounting of the recent positive employment figures:

Another concern is the pattern of “spring boom, summer swoon” in BLS reports since 2010. In each of the past four years, the BLS employment report has shown strong growth in the late winter and early spring, followed by anemic growth in the summer. The winter and spring reports have led to hope for summer growth that then fizzles.

This pattern may be a result of the economic collapse of late 2008 and early 2009 interfering with the BLS seasonal adjustment process. The BLS’s algorithms may “expect” large job losses in the winter and spring that do not materialize, making their seasonally adjusted job reports appear artificially strong.[1] This month’s good numbers could represent a similar statistical mirage, similar to the growth in early 2010 that led the Administration to predict the “recovery summer”[2] that never arrived.[3]

On this topic, the Economic Report of the President, 2013 reports in “Data Watch 2-1: Seasonal Adjustment in Light of the Great Recession” (pages 47-48):

…detailed studies of a wide range of principal economic indicators suggest that the seasonal adjustment techniques that had already been employed by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) adequately accounted for the effects of the Great Recession. BLS analysts calculated alternative seasonal factors for total nonfarm payroll employment after manually excluding the sharp declines that were recorded during the downturn (Kropf and Hudson 2012). This counterfactual experiment failed to generate meaningful revisions to the actual published estimates of total nonfarm payroll employment since January 2010. In fact, the BLS analysts concluded that the implementation of these counterfactual seasonal factors would have revised total nonfarm payroll employment upward by a mere 24,000 jobs over the second and third quarters of 2011 (in other words, an average of 4,000 jobs a month) and downward by just 19,000 jobs over the fourth quarter of 2011 and the first quarter of 2012 (or an average of roughly 3,000 jobs a month). BLS analysts also thoroughly investigated the seasonal adjustment of the Current Population Survey data over the course of the recovery (Evans and Tiller 2012). This inquiry showed that alternative assumptions regarding seasonal adjustment did not meaningfully affect estimates of the unemployment rate since 2007.

While Sherk and Furth’s conjecture predates the release of the ERP, the referenced Kropf and Hudson article predates the Sherk and Furth issue brief by several months. The Kropf and Hudson (2012) article is excellent reading, and I am glad the Heritage Foundation’s random musings drew me to the paper (it saved me a lot of work trying to tease out the seasonals myself!). Chart 2 is particularly illuminating:

seas_adj_great_recession.gif
Source: Kropf, Jurgen, and Nicole Hudson. 2012. “Current Employment Statistics Seasonal Adjustment and the 2007–2009 Recession.” Monthly Labor Review 135, no. 10: 42–53.

The straightforward (and I believe correct) interpretation of the graph is that excluding the Great Recession from the sample period over which the seasonals are estimated does not have a large impact that is consistent with the Sherk and Furth conjecture.

None of the foregoing means that employment growth won’t decrease (I expect it very well might with the sequester going into effect [1]). However, if employment growth decreases, it won’t likely be attributable to a statistical artifact associated with the seasonal adjustment process.

Heritage on Seasonal Adjustment
Menzie Chinn
Thu, 21 Mar 2013 18:40:05 GMT