Daily Archives: 03/30/2011

State of Japan’s Power Grid

 

Nice graphic from the Washington Post:

>

alt


State of Japan’s Power Grid
Barry Ritholtz
Wed, 30 Mar 2011 19:16:09 GMT

Advertisement

Who is Dagny Taggart? Atlas Shrugged Part 1, the Movie, is Coming to Theatres April 15th

I’ve read Atlas Shrugged, and thought it was a good story in two ways.  First, it teaches that people’s professed motives aren’t always their real ones.  Second, it does warn of mindless conformity and politics in one form or another making all decisions.  Otherwise, I’ve always  found her characters to be wooden, and far too preachy of a philosophy that was heartless, ultimately megalomaniacal, as well as Godless.

Furthermore, having seen the fountainhead, the wooden nature of Rand’s character in that film was perhaps greater than in the book.  Difficult as that is to believe.

This post gives me reason enough to want to see the movie.

Who is Dagny Taggart? Atlas Shrugged Part 1, the Movie, is Coming to Theatres April 15th
santitafarella
Fri, 25 Mar 2011 10:43:33 GMT

Atlas Shrugged Part 1, the movie (which depicts the first third of Ayn Rand’s famous novel of ideas) comes into general release on April 15th, and I must say that the following YouTube teaser clip posted by the film’s producers is super-promising:

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                             .

And philosopher David Kelley (a Princeton graduate and author of a widely used textbook) has seen the film and is impressed:

The completed film was shown today for the first time in a private screening. It is simply beautiful. With a screenplay faithful to the narrative and message of the novel, the adaptation is lushly produced. The acting, cinematography, and score create a powerful experience of the story.

Taylor Schilling is riveting as Dagny Taggart, the woman who manages the Taggart Transcontinental rail system with intelligence and courage while fighting interference from the president of the company, her incompetent brother James (Matthew Marsden), and his political cronies. Schilling is well-matched with Grant Bowler as steel-maker Hank Rearden. As the story opens, Rearden has just started producing a new alloy he invented; and Dagny is his first customer. . . .

For over half a century, Rand’s novel has been a lightning rod for controversy. It has attracted millions of devoted fans—and legions of hostile critics. A poor adaptation could be ignored by both sides. This adaptation can’t be ignored. It is way too good. It is going to turbocharge the debate over Rand’s vision of capitalism as a moral ideal. Whether you love the novel or hate it, Atlas Shrugged Part I is a must-see film.

Blogger and Rand enthusiast, Hans Schantz, also attended an invitation-only screening. He was preparing for a big disappointment, but was more-than-pleasantly surprised:

When I heard my favorite novel was being made into a movie, all the available omens boded ill: a “low-budget” production, with “no-name” stars, made independently – without the adult supervision of a real Hollywood studio, and rushed into production at the last minute to avoid loss of rights. It sounded like a recipe for disaster. . . . 

I began to understand – as I should have from the start – that independence is a virtue. Ayn Rand’s challenging prose would never have made it through the filter of a major studio without having been seriously blunted and adulterated. The resulting film would have been a caricature, not a capturing of the novel.

Further, a modest budget enforces an austere simplicity that enhances, rather than dilutes the message. A film with the “big-name” stars variously associated with the project over the years would have been more about the stars than the story. I admit that, in my mind’s eye, I always envisioned an Atlas Shrugged movie as an elaborately stylized visual blending of 1930’s vintage art-deco technology and film noir set in a pseudo-1950’s world with hardboiled, chain-smoking heroes. The film I foolishly thought I wanted would have been a tragic mistake – a mistake that would have transformed Atlas Shrugged into fantasy and undercut the dramatic relevance of Ayn Rand’s ideas to a modern setting. The Spartan, contemporary production is set in the near future, but that quality only serves to make the message more relevant and the story the star.

And of the Rearden YouTube scene posted above, Hans Schantz writes the following:

The released scene is NOT a fluke. It is not an accident. It is a representative sample. The rest of the film really is that good – better actually, because the individual scenes compliment and reinforce each other to create a harmonious whole, true to Rand’s story, superbly executed, and well done. The casting was outstanding, with no weak links.

Barbara Branden also saw the film and is enthusiastic about it:

I am delighted, overwhelmed, and stunned.

Yesterday, I saw Atlas Shrugged Part I, the movie. In advance, I was tense and worried. What if it was terrible? In that case, no one would consider a remake for years, if ever. I didn’t think it would be terrible, especially after I saw a clip from the film : the scene where Rearden comes home to his family after the first pouring of Rearden Metal. The scene was very good indeed. But….

The movie is not so-so, it is not OK, it is not rather good — it is spectacularly good.

This is all great news. Though not a Randian myself, I have always liked Ayn Rand (her blunt, unapologetic, and self-confident atheism and Apollonian-Promethean vision of what human beings can be are an intoxicating draw for me), and I’ve been hoping to see a successful contemporary screen adaptation of one of her novels. It looks like we’ll have one on April 15th.

And I can’t help but wonder whether the first of the three novel adaptations will make for a feminist film. The first third of Ayn Rand’s novel, after all, focuses on Dagny Taggart, a female Promethean fighting for her place in the public realm (a realm traditionally dominated by men). Instead of asking who John Galt is, this first film in the trilogy might inadvertently ask and answer a very different question (though Randians might cringe):

Who is Hillary Clinton?

I’ll be going to the film asking whether I’d want my daughters, when they reach their teens, seeing it, and whether it might prove empowering for them. Dagny Taggart, in the novel, is a refreshing alternative sexual persona: neither the compliant angel nor empty-headed whore, but the intellectual woman; the business woman; the public woman. (The woman weak and stupid men fear.)

Dagny Taggart, the castrating warrior princess?

We’ll see.

Who is Dagny Taggart? Atlas Shrugged Part 1, the Movie, is Coming to Theatres April 15th
santitafarella
Fri, 25 Mar 2011 10:43:33 GMT

Why don’t Tall People Pay the guy in the Airline Seat in Front to Not Recline on them?

That’s what this post below on Economists do it with Models asks.  (By the way when we say models we mean mathematical or econometric models, not attractive members of the opposite sex.  We’re talking about economists come on!)

I thought it was an interesting question.  The responses in the comments generally seemed to be well, people would think you’re a creep or its just not done.  But that doesn’t explain why the custom.

I think it’s at least partially that the cost of negotiation would be high relative to the benefits, also know as transaction costs.  In the seat case you only have one person that can supply you more legroom, and only one person you can sell it to.  There no multitude of buyers and sellers to quickly establish a market price, and no market.  There’s no single price sell your right to recline to at a price that you know is as good as you’d get.

Furthermore, there could be an incentive to move people around on the plane and that would also impose costs on others beyond the folks wanting more legroom or more space. 

Ideally  a market in space behind the seat would I think result in roughly interspaced, people who don’t mind not reclining with people behind who don’t want anyone reclining into their state and seats with those who want to recline with a person not bothered by that (perhaps a small person who is not going to use a laptop) behind. This might mean a lot of seat switching that could delay takeoff.

Fun With The Coase Theorem, Airplane Seat Edition…
econgirl
Mon, 14 Mar 2011 22:27:42 GMT

I am firmly of the belief that people intuitively understand economic principles, even if they don’t consciously recognize them as such. Case in point, from The Consumerist:

It *is* quite an idea, Consumerist readers…in fact, it’s closely related to the Coase theorem. The Coase theorem is best illustrated via an example. From Wikipedia:

Coase developed his theory when considering the regulation of radio frequencies. Competing radio stations could use the same frequencies and would therefore interfere with each others’ broadcasts. The problem faced by regulators was how to eliminate interference and allocate frequencies to radio stations efficiently. What Coase proposed in 1959 was that as long as property rights in these frequencies were well defined, it ultimately did not matter if adjacent radio stations interfered with each other by broadcasting in the same frequency band. Furthermore, it did not matter to whom the property rights were granted. His reasoning was that the station able to reap the higher economic gain from broadcasting would have an incentive to pay the other station not to interfere. In the absence of transaction costs, both stations would strike a mutually advantageous deal. It would not matter whether one or the other station had the initial right to broadcast; eventually, the right to broadcast would end up with the party that was able to put it to the most highly valued use. Of course, the parties themselves would care who was granted the rights initially because this allocation would impact their wealth, but the end result of who broadcasts would not change because the parties would trade to the outcome that was overall most efficient. This counterintuitive insight—that the initial imposition of legal entitlement is irrelevant because the parties will eventually reach the same result—is Coase’s invariance thesis.

Now, I’ll take a bit of creative license and modify the example for the situation at hand:

Econgirl developed her theory when considering the regulation of airline seat reclining. Competing airline customers could use the same space and would therefore interfere with each others’ enjoyment of the flight. The problem faced by regulators was how to eliminate interference and allocate space to airline passengers efficiently. What Econgirl proposed in 2011 was that as long as property rights in these spaces were well defined, it ultimately did not matter if adjacent airline passengers interfered with each other by trying to occupy the same space. Furthermore, it did not matter to whom the property rights were granted. Her reasoning was that the passenger able to reap the higher economic gain from taking up space would have an incentive to pay the other passenger to get out of the way. In the absence of transaction costs, both passengers would strike a mutually advantageous deal. It would not matter whether one or the other passenger had the initial right to take up space; eventually, the right to spread out/recline/etc. would end up with the party that was able to put it to the most highly valued use. Of course, the parties themselves would care who was granted the rights initially because this allocation would impact their wealth, but the end result of who takes up space would not change because the parties would trade to the outcome that was overall most efficient.

For example, if reclining your seat is worth $5 to you, but being able to put my laptop on the tray table is only worth $3 to me, it is efficient for you to recline and me to find another place to put my laptop. If we could negotiate and pay each other off, you will end up reclining your seat regardless of what the airline tells us is the “proper” thing to do. However, if the default is for the stewardess to tell you to not be a jackass and keep your seat up, I will end up with somewhere between $3 and $5 in my pocket as a result of the subsequent negotiation. If, on the other hand, the stewardess tells me to suck it up and let you recline, I won’t get squat in compensation except for perhaps another bag of Doritos munchie mix because the stewardess knows that I’m cranky.

It’s important to note that Coase’s argument only holds when there are no costs or barriers to bargaining. In practice, the efficient outcome may not be reached if the guy behind you thinks you’re a big creeper because you try to pay him in return for him not complaining about the position of your seat. Not that I’ve tried or anything. I’m also pretty confident that it’s only a matter of time until the airlines figure out how to capture the payouts for themselves rather than keeping them within the affected parties…which technically doesn’t affect the efficiency of the outcome but certainly affects the distribution of value.


How difficult it is to reach conclusions just on facts!

Cafe Hayek

via Birther Myth.